Best Selling Books by Robert J Gordon

Robert J Gordon is the author of The Extimation of Prewar GNP Volatility, 1896-1938 (1986), Did Economics Cause World War II? (2008), Beyond monetarism (1982), Macroeconomic Policy in the Presence of Structural (1996), What Caused the Decline in US Business Cycle Volatility? (2005).

81 - 120 of 1,000,000 results
<< >>

The Extimation of Prewar GNP Volatility, 1896-1938

release date: Jan 01, 1986

Did Economics Cause World War II?

release date: Jan 01, 2008
Did Economics Cause World War II?
This is a review article of a new economic history of the Nazi economy by Adam Tooze which cuts through the debate between economics and Hitler''s mistakes as fundamental causes of the outcome. Instead, Tooze argues that the invasion of the Soviet Union was the inevitable result of Hitler''s paranoia about the land-starved backwardness of German agriculture as contrasted with the raw material and land resources of America''s continent and Britain''s empire. The American frontier expansion that obliterated the native Indians provided Hitler with a explicit precedent, which he often cited, for pushing aside the native populations in the east to provide land for German Aryan farmers.

Macroeconomic Policy in the Presence of Structural

release date: Jan 01, 1996

What Caused the Decline in US Business Cycle Volatility?

release date: Jan 01, 2005

What is New-Keynesian Economics?

release date: Jan 01, 1991

Wages and prices are not always sticky : a century of evidence for the U.S., U.K. and Japan

The "End-of-Expansion" phenomenon in short-run productivity behavior

“The” Times-varying NAIRU and Its Implications for Economic Policy

release date: Jan 01, 1996

Macroeconomics

release date: Jan 01, 1987

What Future for the Ju-Wasi of Nyae-Nyae?

release date: Jan 01, 1989

Why U.S. wage and employment behavior differs from that in Britain and Japan

The 1920s and the 1990s in Mutual Reflection

release date: Jan 01, 2005
The 1920s and the 1990s in Mutual Reflection
The uncanny parallel of the stock market boom, bubble, and collapse in 1995-2001 as in 1924-1930, reminds us that business cycles emerge from the complex interplay of multiple factors, not just one.Common elements between the two decades are overshadowed by differences, including the much larger share of agricultural output in the 1920s, the weakness of farm prices throughout the decade, and the role of collapsing farm prices in the pervasive post-1929 downward shift in aggregate demand. Another partly related difference was a high volatility of inventory accumulation that reflected the larger share of agriculture and manufacturing in the economy of the 1920s. Failures of public policy in the 1920s included the absence of deposit insurance, the unit-banking regulations that prevented the diversification of financial risk across regions, and the low margin requirements that exacerbated swings in stock market prices

Evangelization

release date: Jan 01, 1989

Price inertia and policy ineffectiveness in the United States, 1890-1980

Why U.S. Wage and Employment Behaviour Differs from that in Britain and Japan

The Boskin Commission Report : a retrospective one decade later

release date: Jan 01, 2006

The Role of Wages in the Inflation Process

release date: Jan 01, 2005

Five Puzzles in the Behavior of Productivity, Investment, and Innovation

release date: Jan 01, 2004
Five Puzzles in the Behavior of Productivity, Investment, and Innovation
(1) Whatever happened to the cyclical effect? Skeptics were justified on the basis of data through the end of 1999 in their claim that part of the post-1995 productivity growth revival reflected the normal cyclical correlation between productivity and output growth. In contrast data through mid-2003 reveal only a negligible cyclical effect for 1995-99 but rather a temporary bubble in 2002-03. (2) Why did productivity growth accelerate after 2000 when the ICT investment boom was collapsing? The most persuasive argument points to unusually savage corporate cost-cutting and hidden intangible investments in the late 1990s that provided productivity benefits after 2000. (3) The steady decline in the price of computer power implies steady technical progress, but then why did computers produce so little productivity growth before 1995 and so much afterwards? We draw an analogy to electricity, where miniaturization was the key step in making small electric motors practicable, and the internal combustion engine, where complementary investments, especially roads, were necessary to reap benefits. (4) What does the collapse of the investment boom imply about the future of innovation? First-rate inventions in the 1990s, notably the web and user-friendly business productivity software, are being followed by second-rate inventions in the current decade. (5) Finally, why did productivity growth slow down in Europe but accelerate in the U. S.? A consensus is emerging that U. S. institutions foster creative destruction and financial markets that welcome innovation, while Europe remains under the control of corporatist institutions that dampen competition and inhibit new entry. Further, Europe lacks a youth culture like that of the U. S. which fosters independence: U. S. teenagers work after school and college students must work to pay for much of their educational expense. There is a chasm of values across the Atlantic.

The End of the Great Depression 1939-41

release date: Jan 01, 2010
The End of the Great Depression 1939-41
Abstract: Traditional Keynesian multipliers assume that there are no capacity constraints to impede a fiscal-driven expansion in aggregate demand. On the contrary, we find ample evidence of capacity constraints in 1941, particularly in the second half of that year. As a result our preferred government spending multiplier is 1.80 when the time period ends in 1941:Q2 but only 0.88 when the time period ends in supply-constrained 1941:Q4. Only the 1.80 multiplier is relevant to situations like 2009-10 when capacity constraints are absent across the economy

Monetary Policy and the 1979 Supply Shock

Monetary Policy and the 1979 Supply Shock
The most striking aspects of recent U.S. wage and price behavior are the small year-to-year variations in the rate of change of wages, the modest 1977-79 acceleration in the rate of change of both wages and the consumption deflator net of food and energy, and an unprecedented gap between the inflation rates recorded by the CPI and personal consumption deflator. A small and simple econometric model is used to forecast the consequences of various policies for the future growth of the monetary base. No policy will be able to prevent an acceleration in the growth rate of the personal consumption deflator net of food and energy from its recent 7 percent track to 8 percent or above in the first half of 1980. The gross personal consumption deflator will climb even faster, with the difference depending on the behavior of oil and food prices. Thereafter, the effect of slack labor markets will begin to allow inflation net of food and energy to decelerate substantially. A 6 percent rule for the monetary base is too conservative and causes the unemployment rate to rise to 8.5 percent in 1982. An 8 percent rule for the base is preferable, allows the unemployment rate to begin to fall after late 1981, and still achieves a deceleration of inflation net of food and energy from 8 percent in mid-1980 to 6 percent in 1983. Thereafter, the growth of the base should be slowed down to keep the economy from overshooting again
81 - 120 of 1,000,000 results
<< >>


  • Aboutread.com makes it one-click away to discover great books from local library by linking books/movies to your library catalog search.

  • Copyright © 2025 Aboutread.com